Transcript: Interview with Economist Jack Rasmus on Greek Economic Crisis

rasmusThe transcript of Dialogos Radio’s interview with Jack Rasmus, professor of economics and politics at St. Mary’s College in California. This interview aired on our broadcasts for the week of September 15-21, 2016. Find the podcast of this interview here.

MN: Joining us today on Dialogos Radio and the Dialogos Interview Series is Dr. Jack Rasmus, professor of economics and politics at St. Mary’s College in California, economic analyst, and author of such books as “Obama’s Economy: Recovery for the Few,” “Epic Recession: Prelude to Global Depression,” “Systemic Fragility in the Global Economy,” and his most recent book, “Looting Greece.” Dr. Rasmus, thank you for joining us today.

JR: My pleasure.

MN: Recently, Greek Prime Minister Alexis Tsipras gave his annual “state of the nation” address at the Thessaloniki Trade Fair, a speech in which he boasted that the Greek economy has turned the corner, that unemployment is going down, that salaries will be increased, and that the country is returning to growth. Is this what Greece’s economic indicators actually show?

JR: No, not quite. Greece’s debt is still the same as it was in 2011, roughly 180% of GDP. Unemployment has come down since the last debt deal a year ago by only 3-4%, so instead of 27% it’s about 23-24% now. I wouldn’t call that a recovery, that’s depression-level unemployment. All the other indicators in the economy are flat or declining, so I don’t see anywhere that Greece is really “recovering,” and neither really is the entire Eurozone economy. It’s been bouncing along the bottom.

As I said in my book “Systemic Fragility,” in the chapter on Europe, it’s a case of chronic stagnation. They might grow a little, 0.5% or 1% above GDP, most of it as a result of Germany’s growth, then it flattens out or goes below. Most of the periphery economies in Europe are stagnant or in a recession, as they have been for quite some time. It’s really a stretch to say that Greece is recovering.

As far as raising wages, Greece cannot raise, at least in the public sector, any wages without the approval of the troika. As far as the private sector raises, that’s very mixed. It depends on the industry and the sector. But, I think it’s a real stretch to say that Greece is recovering. It’s kind of moving sideways, you might say, in the condition of still chronic economic depression.

MN: One of the perceptions that has been prevalent in global public opinion with regard to the economic crisis in Greece is that the country has been, quote, “bailed out” with billions upon billions of euros in free money. Is this really the case, and where has the so-called “bailout” money towards Greece actually gone?

JR: Countries don’t get bailed out. Governments, banks, businesses, and sometimes, though not so frequently, households get bailed out. So the question is, who got bailed out here, in these last three bailouts, the debt restructuring deals of 2010, 2012, 2015, and a little bit this past spring. The banks got bailed out several times, foreign investors and speculators in Greek bonds and other securities clearly got bailed out in 2012. If you look at where the money has gone, there’s $400 billion in debt in Greece still, that they have to pay off, with an economy that is less than half that size, so it’s impossible.

Where has all this money gone? Recent studies by the European School of Management and Technology documenting at least the 2010 and 2012 bailouts indicate that 95% of all the loans to “bail out” the Greek government, which then bailed out the Greek banks, 95% of that went back to Northern Europe, mostly to the German and Northern European banks that had loaned so much money to Greece. [Bailout funds also went] to the troika, particularly the European Commission (EC), that then distributed it to the banking system and investors in turn. The European Commission is the big bidder here, and to some extent the European Central Bank (ECB) and to a minor extent now, the International Monetary Fund (IMF). So, 95% of all the money loaned to Greece went right back to [Europe] and less than 5% of that went back into the Greek economy.

So who is being bailed out? Well, it’s a flow of bailing out or attempting to prevent the further collapse of the European banking system, which is in a very shaky state right now. Greece has been subsidizing the financial system elsewhere in Europe, as I explain in my analysis.

MN: Much has been said about the Greek public debt, its sustainability, and indeed even its legitimacy. In your view, what needs to be done about the Greek debt?

JR: You might ask what needs to be done about debt throughout the Eurozone, because it’s not just Greece. Greece is perhaps the most serious case, but as we know, other places in the periphery of Europe are still heavily indebted, not just the governments but the banking system as well. You cannot sustain, with austerity measures designed to pay the interest and principal on debt, a $400-plus billion debt based on an economy that’s less than $200 billion. It’s not possible, and even the IMF has come to that conclusion and is maneuvering with the other troika members, the EC, on that particular point. It’s totally unsustainable, it can’t be paid.

Is it legitimate? Well, you have to understand the origins of this debt. It was originally private-sector debt that was created as a result of the creation of the Eurozone in 1999, and the ECB, as part of that creation, and other elements of the Eurozone agreements, particularly what was called the Lisbon Strategy, that Germany adopted. Germany and other Northern European businesses and bankers pumped money and capital into the periphery, including Greece, from 2005 onwards. Germany had a strong competitive advantage in exports, so a lot of the money and capital was pumped into the periphery, including Greece, in order to purchase German and other exports. So the money went in and circulated around, leaving a pile of private sector debt in Greece, Italy, and other places. Then we had the crash of 2008-2009 and the debt could not be repaid, and in steps the troika to loan the governments of Greece and other countries money in order to continue to bail out the private sector and enable the repayment of the private debt. So it starts out as private debt, because of this great imbalance in exports within the Eurozone, and then that gets converted to government debt, and then the big crash of 2008-2009 adds even more debt, and then you have the recession of 2011-2013 in the Eurozone and the 2012 bailout, which piled more debt in order to pay the old debt, and then in 2015 the same thing. So the troika’s piling more debt on Greece in order for Greece to pay the previous debt, and that’s totally unsustainable. You can’t go on that way, and they’re going to have to expunge some of that debt, it’s impossible.

Of course, the Germans, Wolfgang Schauble and the coalition in the north, does not want to allow that and they don’t really want to change the Eurozone, because the Eurozone, while very imbalanced for the periphery, has benefited Germany significantly. So they don’t want to change everything, and they dominate the finance ministers’ council in the EC and they dominate the ECB, and they’re just keeping the situation the way it is because it’s profitable for them that way.

MN: We are speaking with Dr. Jack Rasmus, professor of economics and politics at St. Mary’s College, here on Dialogos Radio and the Dialogos Interview Series, and Dr. Rasmus, you have argued that Greece must nationalize its banking system, and this argument runs contrary to what has been done by the current government and by previous governments in Greece, which have repeatedly bailed out and recapitalized the Greek banking system. Why must Greek banks be nationalized, in your view?

JR: Look at the debt negotiations of 2010, 2012, and 2015. What happened was the ECB, which pretty much controls the Greek central bank—the ECB is just a council of central banks dominated by the Bundesbank [German central bank] and its allies, so they have control, pretty much—and what you saw in the negotiations, as I describe in detail, step-by-step, in my book, is that in 2015, the ECB put the screws to the Greek economy, and SYRIZA collapsed and agreed each time the screws were tightened by the ECB through the Greek central bank, bringing the economy to a halt. They couldn’t deal with the squeeze on the economy by the ECB and the Greek central bank, which is just an appendage of the ECB. They brought, step-by-step, the economy to a halt, squeezing it and of course not releasing loans that they had agreed to provide Greece under previous agreements as well. There was an economic squeeze that SYRIZA did not have a strategy to deal with, and eventually it capitulated and collapsed as the economy was getting worse.

So you’ve got to nationalize, make the Greek central bank and the banking systems independent of the ECB. Gain control over your economy once again, and that is one of several key steps to prevent the squeeze every time you attempt to renegotiate the debt or restructure the debt. Without an independent, Greek, people-controlled banking system, the Eurozone and the troika will squeeze and bring Greece to its knees every time, and we’ve seen that three times. You’ve got to nationalize the banking system, including the central bank, or if you want to just leave the central bank as part of the ECB structure, go ahead, but create an independent central bank authority somewhere else in the Greek government…and there is precedent for that.

In the U.S. during the Great Depression, the U.S. central bank had screwed up badly, and [President] Roosevelt took over and had his Treasury department take over and run the economy essentially. Greece would have to set up a parallel central bank in its finance sector, and pretty much isolate and bypass the influence of the ECB through the Greek central bank. Of course, you would have to create a parallel currency as part of all of this, and impose serious controls on bank withdrawals and capital flows outside the country, which SYRIZA did not really do, because the ECB and the troika were not in favor of it. When you have all the capital, bank withdrawals and capital flight is another way of squeezing the country economically.

MN: The current government in Greece has been continuing a policy of massive privatizations of valuable Greek public assets, with profitable airports and harbors having been privatized in the past year, in addition to the recent selloff of the Greek national railroad for a total of €45 million. What is the short- and long-term impact of the privatization of such key national assets?

JR: The short-term is that when you privatize them, under the aegis and the management control of the troika—the troika has a lot of representatives in Greece now looking over everyone’s shoulder ensuring that they do it the way the troika and particularly the EC wants—the profits, if you sell below market prices, which a lot of these assets are being sold at, that’s profit on the sale for the investors who are buying up these assets. But once the assets are in private hands, where does the revenue go, where does the money flow go? Does it go back into Greece or does it go back into the pockets of the investors and the corporations and the banks outside Greece that are buying it up? Well, it goes out. It’s a form of capital flight. Money that is needed in Greece flows out of Greece, just like the austerity, in general, is imposed to enable the payment of interest and principal on the debt. Well, that is money flowing out of Greece as well.

As I argue in the concluding chapter of my book, this is a new form of financial imperialism, wealth extraction in other words, from the country, that is being structured and managed on a state-to-state basis. It’s not 19th century British imperialism where they set up a factory in India, pay them low wages and bring the textiles back to London and resell at a higher price and so forth. It’s not that kind of production imperialism, this is financial imperialism imposed on Greece, and it’s a new form that’s emerging everywhere, where you indebt the country and then you force the country to engage in austerity in order to pay the principal and interest on the debt and you extract the income from the country, wealth extraction. Privatizations are another form of that. You privatize the public goods, you get them at fire-sale prices if you’re an outsider, and then the income flows from those assets flow back to the coffers of the private companies or the banks or whoever, outside of Greece, and that’s the problem. That’s one of the consequences.

The other consequence is when you privatize, they come in and they cut costs, which means they let off people in mass numbers, they put a hold on wages, they get rid of benefits, and they do everything else for labor cost controls to maximize their revenue and what they get to keep. That’s an immediate consequence as well. Finally, longer-term, it means that Greece has less control over its own economy, if it can’t control its infrastructure and everything is owned by foreigners. Then you can’t influence it as much, and if you’re part of the Eurozone, you’re legally prohibited from what you can do to make sure that these foreign-owned infrastructure companies are behaving in terms of the benefit for the public sector, for the rest of Greece. So that’s the short- and long-term.

MN: Looking beyond just the case of Greece, you have argued in your book, “Systemic Fragility in the Global Economy,” that there are nine major trends which account for the economic troubles that are seen on a global scale. What are some of these trends?

JR: Everywhere, and particularly since 2008, we see central banks and monetary policy to be ascendant here, and that means creating money, pumping it into the economy to bail out the financial systems, the financial institutions, the banks and the shadow banks they talk about in great deal. Shadow banks meaning speculators, hedge funds, private equity firms, asset management companies and so forth. Bail them out, that’s the whole thing, and we see a massive money bailout of tens of trillions of dollars since 2008. All of that liquidity injection into the economy has driven interest rates down to zero or even, in Europe and Japan and other places, negative rates, and that of course fuels debt. With rates that cheap, corporations and businesses just float new corporate bonds, and they use the money not to invest necessarily, they use it to buy back the stock and drive up the stock prices and pay out dividends, or they sit on it, they hoard it, or they send it to emerging markets. That’s a problem everywhere, and that’s the result of massive liquidity injections, which have really been escalating since the 1980s, when they eliminated everywhere controls on international capital flows.

In the 1970s, when the Bretton Woods system collapsed and central banks took over, the combination of those has led to the financialization of the global economy in the 21st century, where profits are far greater for investing and speculating in financial securities than they are in investing in real assets and real things that create real jobs and real income and real consumption. We’re becoming dependent on debt more and more. The economy is credit and debt driven more and more, and that’s the result of this massive liquidity injection, and it also leads to a shift from real asset investment—investing in real things that create jobs that people need—a shift towards financial asset investment. That means that real investment collapses over time and productivity collapses over time as well, and we see that happening everywhere, to different speeds and different degrees.

That’s a major point that I argued about in my book, “Systemic Fragility,” this financialization of the global economy based on liquidity and debt and squeezing out, it’s diverting money and capital from real investment into financial speculation. You’ve got to understand what’s going on in Greece is a concrete expression of this, the reliance on financial means and financial manipulation, because that’s what’s happening in Greece and the periphery. The periphery in the Eurozone is at a great disadvantage to Germany and others, and they’re being manipulated financially. All the payments on interest and the debt flow back to the north, 95% is really subsidizing the banks in the north. This is all flowing through the EC to the private sector, and it’s a nice constant money capital flow from interest payments and privatization and speculation on government bonds and securities and stocks in these countries as the volatility occurs. It’s a reflection, in Greece, of what’s happening on a broader scale elsewhere in the global economy, and that’s why we haven’t seen much of a recovery in the global economy. Global trade is stagnant and real investment everywhere is drifting towards zero, productivity is negative almost everywhere, even in the U.S., and we’re seeing growth rates of barely one percent, 1.5% at best, when it should be double that. We see these growing, non-performing bank loans, almost $2 trillion in Europe, the worst in Italy with about $400 billion. We see the same thing in Japan and in China, trillions in negative interest rates and in non-performing bank loans. We’re becoming more systemically fragile financially because of this shift to financial speculation.

MN: We are on the air with Dr. Jack Rasmus, professor of economics and politics at St. Mary’s College, here on Dialogos Radio and the Dialogos Interview Series, and Dr. Rasmus, looking at Europe, there are increasing warning signs across all sorts of major economic institutions, ranging from Deutsche Bank to the Italian banking system. What is your outlook for the Eurozone economy and the difficulties that it is currently facing?

JR: The European banking system has never fully recovered from the 2008-2009 crash. It’s being bailed out, as I described. The ECB is pumping money into the banking system in various ways, long-term refinancing options and all the bailout funds and qualitative easing and negative interest rates and so forth. They’re desperately pumping money into the banking system, but the banks aren’t really lending, at least to those businesses that would reinvest in real assets to create jobs and so forth. It’s far more profitable to make money now, investors make money from financial speculation, than they do from investing long-term and expecting to get a return over 10-20 years for investment in a real company that creates real things.

The banking system has not really recovered in Europe, and we can see the strains now with the non-performing loans, in particular in Italy. Of course, we know the situation with the non-performing bank loans in Greece. Portugal is in bad shape as well in terms of non-performing loans, and now we see even places like Deutsche Bank and others beginning to feel this strain, and the further impact on the Euro banking system of “Brexit,” a lot more uncertainty and so forth as a result of “Brexit,” the British leaving, even though they are not a part of the Eurozone. A lot of uncertainty and fragility and, after eight years, no real recovery in the banking system even though it’s been bailed out—in other words, the central banks have pumped trillions into the private banking system.

But the problem is that the private banks are either hoarding the cash, they won’t invest in real growth, or they’re sending their money offshore to emerging markets, at least for a while they were, to China and so forth, or they’re using it, as in the U.S., to buy back stock and pay out dividends and loaning money to companies to do just that. The global economy and global financial system has changed dramatically in ways that make it much more fragile than it’s ever been before. A lot of debt has been building up everywhere: over $50 trillion in additional debt has occurred since 2009, and when the next recession comes, how are they going to pay that debt? When times are stable or growing, you can add debt without a great crisis emerging, but when you have a recession or a downturn that’s significant, where are you going to get the money capital to pay the principal and interest on the debt? Then you start seeing defaults and you start seeing financial asset price collapses going on, and now you’re back in 2008-2009. That’s the picture of the global economy. In other words, Europe and European banks are a fragile point globally, just as Japanese and Chinese banks are, although most of the Chinese banks are nationalized—I’m talking about the shadow banks in China—and different places in emerging markets, those places dependent on commodity exports, particularly oil, they’re in very fragile condition as well.

MN: Do you believe that Italy will be the first domino to fall, as far as departure from the Eurozone?

JR: No, I don’t believe Italy will depart from the Eurozone, although you never know, we’ll see what the vote is here. I predict that the government won’t get the vote that it wants, it’s a 50-50 chance. I don’t see Italy leaving, Italy is too dependent on the Eurozone, the central bank and so forth, to keep its banking system afloat. I don’t see that they will exit. What happens next spring is going to be more important, with elections in Germany and in France, and it’s quite possible, not impossible at least, that the National Front, which has called for a referendum, may prevail in those elections in France. I think that is more of an important development than Italy.

MN: We are speaking with Dr. Jack Rasmus, professor of economics and politics at St. Mary’s College, here on Dialogos Radio and the Dialogos Interview Series, and Dr. Rasmus, turning back to the case of Greece, what do you believe would be the best policy option and what would be the steps for Greece to follow, in your view, in order to escape the spiral of economic depression and austerity? Do you believe, for instance, that a Eurozone exit is the solution? You mentioned the imposition of a parallel currency, for instance.

JR: SYRIZA made it clear from the beginning, when it came into power, that it was not in favor of “Grexit,” and it has always maintained that position. An unprepared, “we’re leaving the Eurozone and the euro” kind of decision would cause a collapse of values, particularly those who have investments in some savings in Greece. A lot of those savings are outside the country now. To some extent, SYRIZA was caught between a rock and a hard place here. They couldn’t or didn’t want to advocate an exit, and at least those who had investments didn’t want it because of the potential effect on their investments. The broader Greek populace thinks, still, that to be European you have to be in the Eurozone. That’s a big mistake, I think, but as far as “Grexit,” just a pure exit, no, I don’t think that would do it.

I think what Greece and SYRIZA should have done is to create a parallel currency and to take over its banking system. In other words, make the banking system truly independent, including the Greek central bank, and if that was not possible, bypass the Greek central bank and set up a central banking function in the finance ministry, as the U.S. has done at different times. Create a parallel currency, and policies and programs to get people to convert their euros into the parallel currency. Maybe declare that henceforth all taxes to the Greek government will be paid with the parallel currency, and that means that people would then trade in their euros for the parallel currency to pay their taxes. There’s other measures to strengthen the value, within Greece, of the new parallel currency and lower the value of the euro. Then tell the troika that we’re going to pay you in your euros, but if we run out of euros here as a result of the conversion, well, tough luck, we don’t have a way of paying you, let’s negotiate a final deal where you expunge some of it and we pay you off and we go our separate ways. Of course, you would have to create significant capital flow controls, which has always been a problem every time there’s been a crisis, the money flows out of Greece.

So, an independent banking system, plus a parallel currency, plus strict capital outflow controls, and in steps, step-by-step, take the economy out of the control of the troika without a formal exit. That could have been done, but for some reason SYRIZA and its finance advisers either didn’t want to do that or didn’t know how to do that.

MN: Arguments that have been heard against the imposition of a parallel currency include the argument that the existence of two currencies would create a situation where there would be “haves” and “have nots”–between those who would have a stronger, hard currency in their hands, compared to a weaker, devalued domestic currency in their hands. How do you respond to this argument?

JR: There are policies and approaches you can take that entice and require people to convert their euros into the new currency. That would raise the demand and therefore the value, the price of the new currency. If you just had the currency and you didn’t have this forced trade-in, then of course you would have “haves” and “have nots,” the new currency would collapse, and pretty soon no one would want to use it. But, for example, saying that taxes could only be paid with the new currency, would force people who had corporations and businesses and so forth to purchase the new currency with the euro. It would undermine the value of the euro in Greece and it would raise the value of the new currency in Greece as well. That might set off a parallel elsewhere in the Eurozone with other countries thinking the same thing, which would undermine the value of the euro and put the squeeze on the troika for once. Greece never put the squeeze on the troika, it was just the opposite in all of these negotiations that occurred, they never really hurt the troika in negotiations, and that’s the only way you really prevail in negotiations. You’ve got to make it unpleasant for the opposition. SYRIZA never did that, they just played along and according to the rules of the troika and made concession after concession in 2015.

SYRIZA thought, Tsipras and others thought, that their example would strike a spark elsewhere in Europe of other social democratic forces and movements and even governments in Europe, like France. They thought that they would get the rest of the social democracies behind them and together they would reform the entire Eurozone. Well, that was a fiction, that was a fantasy thought on the part of Tsipras and others, but that was the core of their whole strategy, getting the social democrats in the European Commission and getting Ollande and others on our side, and together creating a new infrastructure and investment. But that was a fantasy. European social democracy is a dying force throughout Europe, and that’s why you see the growth on the fringes, both to the right and the left, of other parties, because European social democracy has abandoned its role in Europe, and you see the polarization going on.

Tsipras’ and Varoufakis’ problem was that they thought they could get all these liberal elements behind them and that together they would have enough weight to force Wolfgang Schauble and other finance ministers to make concessions. Well, Schauble and the other ministers, the “German faction,” the “German coalition,” as I call it, within the finance ministers’ council in the European Commission remained dominant. At every step along the way, whenever SYRIZA and its few allies tried to make a compromise where some concessions were made to them, the German faction and coalition just squelched it. We saw that, for example, at the very end, when you just had the referendum vote in July 2015. We saw that very clearly there. Greece has the vote, and the vote says go back and negotiate a better deal for us, and what does Tsipras do? He totally caves in to the Schauble faction and so forth, and then the Schauble faction says “the offer we made last week is now off the table, now you’re going to have to accept an even worse one.” So they really put the screws to SYRIZA and SYRIZA looked to its allies in the EC, and they totally caved in as well and said “well, okay, this is the fact, we can’t really influence the Germans, you’ll have to accept something worse.” And then things just got worse and worse until you had the final agreement on August 20, 2015.

If you look at the actual development, which I describe in great detail, step-by-step, from January 2015 through the new parliamentary elections in September 2015, it was just a step-by-step retreat, because SYRIZA had the wrong strategy and was not engaged in certain tactics that were necessary. Of course, the troika itself had a lot of cards to play. It would have been an uphill fight for SYRIZA anyway. The time where they might have really been able to strike some concessions from the troika was 2012, but New Democracy was totally in the pocket of the troika, so that was impossible. So we’ve had a retreat ever since.

I’ve written about what happened this past spring, with the secret discussions of the IMF with the troika to bring to a head more concessions and more debt imposed on Greece, which before the July debt payments came due in Greece, because the IMF and the troika were worried about a “Brexit” and what impact that might have on renewing “Grexit.” So they put the screws to Greece again in the spring, raised the debt even more, austerity even more, and I think another round of that is coming, because the IMF wants out of the troika deal. We’ll see what happens at the IMF meeting, but they haven’t endorsed even the 2015 agreement, because they know it’s unsustainable. I think the IMF is maneuvering to have the European Commission to buy its portion of the debt, and once that happens, the EC will demand even more austerity from Greece.

MN: In the event that a parallel currency is successfully implemented and steps are taken to maintain or even strengthen its value, could that be a prelude to a switch to a national, domestic currency?

JR: Yes. At some point, one currency will become dominant. You can’t have two equal currencies like that. Another advantage of the new currency is that it will initially start out at less value than the euro, and that will be used as the trading currency. That will stimulate Greek exports to elsewhere, outside the Eurozone.

Part of the problem is that the periphery in Europe is so dependent on exports and imports to Germany and the north, that it can’t really engage in its own independent export strategy without cutting wages. Throughout Europe, you have what’s called “internal devaluation” going on, when you are stuck with a currency and someone else’s central bank, the ECB and the euro. You can’t really engage in independent monetary policy to stimulate your economy and you can’t engage in lowering your currency in order to gain some advantage in exports. You’re stuck, and only the most powerful country that’s most efficient and has the lowest costs is able to take advantage of global exports using the currency that it has, and that’s Germany. The weaker economies of the periphery will always be at a disadvantage to Germany, relatively, when it comes to trying to push their exports anywhere else outside the Eurozone. That’s the lesson here. The lesson is that you’ve got a 1999 agreement in which you have this quasi-central bank, the ECB, and you have this currency, and that arrangement significantly benefits the most efficient, low-cost producer, which is Germany, at the expense of the periphery and those who are less efficient and low-cost. Until you have a true central bank and a fiscal union to some extent, that will pump the money into the periphery to help it grow when it doesn’t, you will always have the situation you have in Europe right now.

Compare that to the United States, where there’s a fiscal union, so that if certain states have economic problems…the federal government can pump the money into those specific locations. But if you don’t have a true federal government and fiscal union, you can’t do that, and if your central bank is dominated by the largest economy—Germany—well, even the monetary policy has no effect. And if it’s a single currency, it’s to the advantage of the stronger economy at the disadvantage of the weaker.

The whole Eurozone economy is structured to emphasize the growth of the strongest economies at the expense of the weaker, and that’s not going to change. It’s built in to the Eurozone. You cannot create a currency union and a customs union without a true banking union and fiscal union, and they’re finding that out. More and more countries in the Eurozone are beginning to come to that conclusion, but it was foreordained. People knew this, economists knew this from the very beginning, and that’s the tragedy. Greece has tied its tail to the Eurozone, dominated by Germany, and it can never get out of this situation as long as Germany dominates the institutions, which it does, because the whole arrangement is great for Germany. That’s why they don’t want to change anything.

MN: To wrap up, share with us a few words about your most recent book, “Looting Greece,” published by Clarity Press. What can readers expect to find in your book, and where can our listeners find out more about your books and your writings?

JR: They can go to my blog, jackrasmus.com, and on the sidebar there is a photo of the jacket of the book, “Looting Greece.” It’s all available there, so is my “Systemic Fragility in the Global Economy” book, published earlier this year, which is really an overview of the total global economy and this whole financialization issue that I talked about. The Greece book is really a case study of the consequences of financialization and globalization and integration which is occurring. I argue that there is this phenomenon of the smaller economies being tied in to the larger economies through all of these free trade agreements, which lead to currency unions, which lead to banking unions, and then you’ve got a situation like Greece and the euro periphery and the problems associated with that. The book “Looting Greece” is also a historical look at the origins of the Greek debt, that starts in 1999 with the Eurozone, the adoption of the euro by Greece in 2002, and the consequences of all that, how this debt developed, first in the private sector because of German export domination and then conversion of the private debt in 2008-2009 to the public debt, and then of course the collapse of 2008-2009, which added to the government debt. And then, you had the 2012 agreement where the private sector was bailed out, and that added more debt, and then 2015 and so forth. Debt on debt, to repay interest and principal of debt.

All this is described in great detail in the early chapters, and then most of the book is a step-by-step, blow-by-blow of the negotiations between SYRIZA, on the one hand, and the troika on the other hand, from January [2015] through the spring of 2016, and what were the strategic and tactical errors of SYRIZA, and what were the strategic and tactical moves by the troika which enabled it to prevail. And then at the end, it’s really about how this is a form of a new emerging financial and wealth extraction from smaller economies by the larger economies, because of this globalization and integration arrangement that exists, and the emergence of financial extraction and financial exploitation, which is going on more and more and how central banks are feeding that all, which will lead to my next book, which is about global central banks and the problems they’ve created as we move to another crisis, which I think is coming in the next five years.

MN: Well, Dr. Rasmus, thank you very much for joining us today here on Dialogos Radio and the Dialogos Interview Series, and for sharing your insights with us.

JR: Yes, and if anyone is interested and wants to ask me additional questions about this, they can just e-mail me at drjackrasmus [at] gmail.

MN: Wonderful, well Dr. Rasmus, thank you once again.

JR: My pleasure.

Please excuse any typos or errors which may exist within this transcript.

print

Comments are closed.